Computer Laboratory Home Page Search A-Z Directory Help
University of Cambridge Home Computer Laboratory
Economics and Law
Computer Laboratory > Course material 2002-03 > Economics and Law

Economics and Law
2002-03

Taught by: Dr Ross Anderson, Dr Robert Evans, Mr Nicholas Bohm and Mr Richard Clayton.
Taken by: Part IB

Syllabus

Introduction

At one level, this course provides a bridge between the professional practice and ethics course in part 1a and the courses in business and e-commerce in part 2. But that is not all.

Economic arguments are starting to appear in a surprising number of areas of computer science. Economics deals with mechanisms whereby global equilibria emerge from the behaviour of large numbers of agents who optimise their utility locally. Economic arguments and techniques are starting to be used by computer scientists to tackle problems from network congestion, through resource allocation in distributed operating systems, to security. As systems become ever larger, these techniques are likely to become more important. (I got roped into teaching this course because of my interest in the interaction between economics and information security.)

Useful though economic arguments and explanations may be, however, there are many reasons why market mechanisms may fail, or yield an equilibrium that is far from the social optimum. Law deals with rules developed to remedy this. As the Internet has changed from a research tool to a public utility over the past ten years, legal questions have become increasingly important to computer scientists.

One word of warning, though. Many part 1b students may never have studied a humanties subject above the GCSE level. It is a different task from learning a programming language; it is not sufficient to acquire proficiency at a small core of manipulative techniques, and figure out the rest when needed. Breadth matters. You should spend at least half of the study time you allocate to this subject on general reading. There are many introductory texts on economics and on law; your college library is probably a good place to start.

Classical economics

The first two lectures will look at the classical view of economics: that under certain assumptions, markets provide an optimal way of allocating resources. This view had its roots in Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations and was further developed by writers such as Ricardo and Jevons to provide an explanation of the forces driving the industrial revolution. We'll explore concepts such as comparative advantage, marginal utility, opportunity cost and exchange, so that you get at least a rough idea of what's `under the hood'.

We will then look briefly at a number of the ways in which classical economic models fail, including the criticisms of Keynes and the fact that efficiency, welfare and justice do not always coincide.

There is a huge literature on basic economics. Cambridge economics students cut their teeth on Varian's textbook, `Intermediate Microeconomics', of which your college library should have many copies. You might look at chapters 1-6 and 14-16 to begin with. For an entirely different perspective, try JK Galbraith's `History of Economics'. A very convenient online reference is the History of Economic Thought website. With the collapse of the Soviet Union and the growth of anti-globalisation protests, trade is perhaps the most controversial topic nowadays: the consensus view of economists is probably well represented by Steven Suranovic's notes.

Information economics

Of greater interest for computer scientists, however, are some more modern criticisms of the classical approach that fall within the realm of microeconomics rather than of macroeconomics or social theory.

Information goods and services markets tend to be characterised by high fixed costs, low marginal costs and increasing returns to scale, together with lock-in effects, all of which tend to lead to monopoly or oligopoly. In many markets, there are also network effects: the more people use a given service, the more value it is to each user. So products may take a long time to reach critical mass, then take off very rapidly (as happened with faxes in 1985-88 and email ten years later). Network effects can reinforce a tendency to monopoly.

We will look at a number of other ways in which information goods and services markets can deviate from the classical ideal. These include asymmetric information, where one party to a contract knows more than the other. For example, people applying for health insurance typically know more about their health than the insurance company does, and this leads to adverse selection effects whereby sick people buy more cover. (Attitudes to risk in general are well known to be perverse; see John Adams on Cars, Cholera and Cows.)

The strategies used by monopolies to maximise their revenue are important, both as a practical foundation for later work on e-commerce and as a theoretical underpinning for understanding regulation. These include marget segmentation, price differentiation and bundling. Why, for example, does Microsoft prefer to sell Office as a single product rather than as separate word processor, spreadsheet and other programs?

By far the best book on this is Shapiro and Varian's `Information Rules'. Varian's textbook also has some useful material, especially in chapters 32-36. As for online resources, there are many: the Information Economy page at Berkeley is a reasonable place to start.

Game theory

Game theory provides useful tools for understanding monopoly and oligopoly behaviour. For example, suppose that it costs $250 to fly a passenger from Boston to London and back, and only two airlines comnpete on the route. How will they set prices? Will they collude and charge $500 each, making a healthy profit, or will they compete for market share and charge $300 or even $255? What sort of strategies are available, and what sort of equilibria might emerge?

One of the classic puzzles in game theory is the Prisoner's dilemma. Two crooks are arrested and questioned separately about a robbery. The police tell each of them that if he confesses, he will go free while his partner will get 10 years for the robbery. If he keeps quiet and his partner confesses, it will be the other way round. If both confess, they will get five years; while if neither confesses, they will get a year each for possessing a firearm. Here, the optimal strategy from the prisoners' collective viewpoint is for both to keep quiet, but if they cannot both trust the other then the optimal strategy for each individual is to confess.

This is typical of many problems encountered in real life. Resolving them is easier where the games are not isolated, but are part of a series. Then one might, for example, have a strategy of tit for tat - if you cooperate with me this round, I'll return the favour next time; but if you stab me in the back, I'll retaliate. There has been a lot of study of such strategies; they are important not just in economics, but also in fields such as evolutionary biology where the evolution of strategies is believed to be the foundation for much social behaviour in animals.

There are many books and web pages, such as Game Theory .net and the Stanford Encyclopaedia of Philosphy. (Of particular interest to computer scientists is the work of Robert Axelrod, one of the pioneers of the evolution of cooperation, who ran regular tournaments of interated prisoner's dilemma which contributed to the development of genetic programming ideas.)

Auction theory

A lot of current work in auction theory spills over between economics and computer science. Auctions have been around since at least the times of ancient Greece; they have long been the traditional way of selling art, livestock and much else. A lot of money was invested during the dotcom boom on the premise that technology would so lower the transaction costs associated with auctions that they would become the dominat means of doing business in many sectors. Ebay grew from nothing to blue-chip status in a few years; and the UK government made billions from auctioning off spectrum for third-generation mobile phones.

A surprising number of things can go wrong with auctions. The British government's success was not replicated everywhere else; in a number of countries, phone companies managed to rig the auctions and get bandwidth cheaply. Often this didn't require any overt criminal behaviour; the rules of the auctions were such that players could signal to each other, during the bidding process, which blocks they were interested in. The resulting tacit collusion meant that the taxpayers in many places got much less than expected. (The UK government's adviser, Paul Klemperer, has some interesting papers on what people did wrong - see especially `What Really Matters in Auction Design' for the practicalities. For a proof of the Revenue Equivalence Theorem, see his Guide to the Literature, and for its applications see Why Every Economist Should Learn Some Auction Theory.)

At the theoretical end of things, there has been a huge surge of interest among computer science researchers in the design of combinatorial auctions. A combinatorial auction is one in which you can bid for combinations of objects: `I'll give you $100 for lots 1 and 4 and 7, or I'll give you $80 for lots 3 and 4 and 7'. Finding an optimal allocation in such an auction is not merely an NP-complete problem, but is close to many engineering problems of practical interest - such as finding a low-cost route across a network. (For more detail and links, see the notes of a course at Berkeley by Christos Papadimitriou.)

Introduction to law

There will be two talks on legal topics. The first, by Nicholas Bohm of the Law Society's Electronic Law Committee, will cover the basics. As the syllabus puts it: contract and tort; copyright and patent; liabilities and remedies; competition law; choice of law and jurisdiction. The gloss on that is: what do you have do do online in order to incur liability, or to impose it on someone else; and where can you be pursued, or pursue them, through the courts once you have done so?

The second talk, by Richard Clayton of FIPR, looks at more specific issues of law and regulation. There are a number of EU directives which affect how you can do business on the net, covering subjects that range from distance selling, electronic commerce, data protection and electronic signatures to copyright; there are a number of particular issues relating to their UK implementation. There are also some specific UK laws, such as the Regulation of Investigatory Powers Act, that one might have to watch out for.

Intellectual property

The course title `economics and law' also refers to the academic discipline whose subject matter centres on copyright, patent, and related topics such as database rights. This will be the topic of the final lecture.

Intellectual property is increasingly seen as the foundation of prosperity in the information age, but is increasingly controversial. Powerful lobby groups, such as Hollywood and the music industry, have pushed for increased legal protection in ways that have brought them into conflict with the computer industry and with liberties groups. See for example the talk given at the Computer Lab by Richard Stallman this March. For an anlysis of the economic effects, see papers by Scotchmer, especially ``The Law and Economics of Reverse Engineering''.

Even within Cambridge University, there has been controversy at a plan by the Vice Chancellor to assume ownership and control of all intellectual property rights generated by faculty and research students. In fact, one of the reasons why these lecture notes are so short is that I have spent much of the past couple of months helping organise resistance to these plans; another is that if they go through, the copyright on lecture notes like these will no longer be mine but the University's (so if I ever incorporate them up into a book, I might have to share the royalties). I may refer to work by Friedman and Silberman on academic incentives; there is a lot more material linked from here. The best-regarded cyber-law course is that taught at Berkeley by Pam Samuelson; the notes are here.

So `economics and law' is still a breaking story, and I hope to bring the news from the trenches.

Supervisions

This course has been created by amalgamating and extending some of the basic material in the part 2 E-commerce and Business studies courses. Some previous Tripos questions that are still relevant are here, here, and here. In addition to this, see the revision questions in Varian's textbook, chapters 1-6, 14-17, 24-25, 27-28 and 32-36, and the problems in its companion volume of `Workouts in Intermediate Microeconomics'.